Clarisa Long*
Part I of a two-part series of articles on international intellectual
property protection.
International piracy of intellectual property rights has emerged
as one of the most important foreign policy issues for many industrialized
countries, particularly the United States. U.S. companies have suffered
greatly from the lack of rigorous and uniform international standards
for intellectual property rights. The absence of intellectual property
laws in developing countries costs U.S. firms one dollar for every
three dollars of revenue gained from exported products, PhRMA, Opportunities
and Challenges for Pharmaceutical Innovation 3 (1996), while inadequate
international enforcement of existing laws is estimated to cost
U.S. industry up to $80 billion per year. Report of the United States
Trade Representative's Intergovernmental Policy Advisory Committee
(IGPAC) to the Congress of the United States on the Agreements Reached
in the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations 22 (1994).
New technologies remain one of the main sources of this country's
economic growth. Because intellectual property is relied upon, in
one form or another, by almost every segment of the economy, protecting
intellectual property assets abroad is crucial to maintaining our
position as an innovative leader.
The scope of intellectual property rights granted, and the degree
to which those laws are enforced, reflect what a nation considers
to be its best interest. The level of protection in industrialized
countries is generally high, whereas intellectual property protection
in the developing world varies widely, with many products excluded
from protection altogether. Although the United States extends patent
protection to seeds and plants, for example, the intellectual property
laws of many developing countries explicitly or implicitly exclude
most agricultural inventions. Until recently Brazil denied protection
for pharmaceutical products on the grounds that private property
rights for pharmaceuticals would make the products prohibitively
expensive and would create technological dependency. The enthusiasm
with which intellectual property rights are enforced by developing
country governments varies even more than the level and scope of
protection.
Because of minimal standards of protection and lax enforcement
throughout the developing world, pirates have been able to copy
a wide range of U.S. name-brand goods and protected products, invading
other foreign markets and even the United States with them. The
widespread extent of the problem, coupled with increasing concern
on the part of businesses, has made protecting intellectual property
on a worldwide basis a major component of the U.S. foreign policy
agenda. The U.S. government has undertaken efforts to strengthen
world-wide protection of intellectual property rights through bilateral
consultations with problem countries and multilateral fora such
as the General Agreement of Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Most developing
countries have committed, pursuant to recent treaties, to raise
their standards of intellectual property protection within a grace
period. How quickly increased standards of protection will be adopted,
and what form those standards will take, remains an open question.
It should be noted that although the terms "piracy,"
"counterfeiting," and "infringement" are frequently
used interchangeably when discussing violations of intellectual
property rights, they do not mean the same thing. Infringement is
a legal term of art, and it refers to violations of a cognizable
legal right for which redress can be sought in the courts. Piracy
and counterfeiting are generic terms for all unauthorized uses of
intellectual property, and they usually refer to copying products
for financial gain. The distinction is an important one, because
much of what U.S. businesses refer to as infringement is really
copying of products for which most developing countries provide
no legal protection and for which businesses have no recourse in
foreign courts.
With the globalization of the world economy, developing countries
are finding that maintaining competitiveness is a critical factor
in development. Economists in the industrialized and developing
world alike agree that the ability to develop and commercialize
applied knowledge -- the end products of research and development
-- is the main source of a country's economic growth. The lack of
intellectual property protection in developing countries has generated
a hostile environment for foreign and domestic investment that has
hampered the economic growth potential of those countries. As policymakers
in developing countries struggle to attract investment and world-class
technologies to their shores, they are slowly realizing that, in
the words of Yogi Berra, "we have seen the enemy and it is
us."
The developing world is plagued by two problems with respect to
intellectual property: a lack of formal laws providing an adequate
scope of protection, and failure to enforce existing laws against
violators. Most developing countries do not possess a legal tradition
of protecting intellectual property rights. Although formal protection
is available on paper in most developing countries, enforcement
is largely nonexistent and even the best enforcement efforts are
weak. The existence of formal laws without effective enforcement
is as bad as the absence of laws altogether.
While the U.S. regards intellectual property rights as comparable
to rights to physical property, developing countries use intellectual
property protection as an economic policy variable. Developing nations
have traditionally considered intellectual property to be the heritage
of humanity, rather than an asset to be privately held. The resistance
to strong protection for intellectual property rights is actually
encouraged by the open support of international organizations. For
example, the policy recommendations of the United Nations Committee
on Technology and Development have been based on the assumption
that weak intellectual property protection benefits less developed
countries.
One of the reasons cited by developing nations for lax protection
is that they fear the industrialized world would come to hold a
monopoly on innovative technologies, particularly in the field of
biotechnology, and would produce drugs and agricultural products
that would be sold to the developing world at a high price. Developing
countries have traditionally been forced to import high technology
goods and services. As a result, there are few local interest groups
or trade groups sponsoring strong protection of intellectual property
rights.
Another reason for lax enforcement is that many developing countries
have very successful pirate industries. For example, the pirate
pharmaceutical industry in Argentina, one of the most consistent
violators of intellectual property rights, is worth $4.6 billion
and supplies the rest of Latin America with pirated copies of U.S.-patented
pharmaceuticals. Its lobby, CILFA, is one of the five most active
pharmaceutical lobbying groups in the world, and has been estimated
to contribute an average of $60 million per year to the political
campaigns of those members of the Argentine Senate and Chamber of
Deputies who oppose the implementation of stronger patent laws.
Pharmaceutical and software firms in Argentina opposing enhanced
intellectual property protection, and their associations, have consistently
outspent foreign firms and their trade associations by a margin
of nine to one. Mark Siegelman, Department of Commerce, "Intellectual
Property Protection: Argentina" 8-14 (n.d.) (unpublished manuscript).
Political and business leaders in the developing world realize
that raising the standards of intellectual property protection will
create long-term benefits but short-term costs. Enforcing intellectual
property rights are seen by politicians in developing countries
as hampering their chances for reelection and, among other things,
reducing campaign contributions made by lobbies representing local
pirate industries. The benefits of defining and enforcing intellectual
property rights, on the other hand, are more distant and less tangible.
When governments are unstable, and when politicians do not expect
to gain the long-term benefits of legal reforms, they do not have
the incentive to make those reforms.
To the extent that developing countries grant formal protection
for intellectual property, they often take away with the left hand
what they have bestowed with the right. Three techniques developing
countries use to weaken the protection afforded by intellectual
property rights are issuing compulsory licenses, allowing parallel
imports, and applying a working requirement test.
Many developing countries have traditionally imposed compulsory
licensing agreements as a condition precedent to granting and enforcing
intellectual property rights. For example, in many developing countries,
if a patentee wants sell a patented product, the patentee is required
to license, on fixed-rate royalty terms, the right to make, use,
and sell that product. Local intellectual property holders are only
marginally affected by such conditions because at present, only
1% of royalties from the licensing of intellectual property are
generated by developing country nationals. See Carlos Prima Braga,
The North-South Debate on Intellectual Property Rights, in Global
Rivalry and Intellectual Property (1991). The U.S. has always opposed
compulsory licensing clauses, particularly if they are coupled with
fixed royalty payments.
Most developing countries also attempt to undercut the market power
of a foreign national by allowing parallel imports -- that is, by
allowing competitors, who have acquired the right to use a patent
abroad, to sell a copy of the patented product locally in direct
competition with the original owner of a patent.
Finally, a working requirement test means that unless the holder
of a patent uses or produces the innovation within the national
territory, other producers wishing to use the patented technique
will be entitled to a license even without the patentee's consent.
This strategy of weakening and destabilizing intellectual property
protection, although perceived by developing country governments
to be in their best interest, conflicts sharply with the view of
intellectual property held by the U.S. Because much intellectual
property is produced only after considerable financial investment,
the actual, perceived, and expected losses on the part of U.S. firms
due to inadequate intellectual property protection influence the
willingness of firms to transfer technology to the developing world.
The problem is compounded by the fact that piracy is easier than
ever before. Today's high technology products, such as computer
software and hardware, biotechnology, and pharmaceuticals, are extraordinarily
information-intensive. It is the information contained in the innovation
that is valuable, and digitized information can be copied with the
touch of a button. (In contrast, when the value of an innovation
is determined by its physical structure, and not by the cost of
R&D, the marginal cost of copying is much higher.) Computer
software, for example, is expensive to develop but easy to copy.
In the pharmaceutical industry, the discovery process is extraordinarily
resource-intensive, but once an effective drug is on the market,
the compound is comparatively easy to synthesize. A copyist does
not even need to invest much energy or creativity in figuring out
how to copy a product, because U.S. law requires that the producer
of the product reveal to the world how to make and use the product
in exchange for receiving a patent.
The ease of copying is a relatively new development in the history
of technology. Until a few decades ago, a person who attempted to
pirate and mass-produce copies of a book in violation of copyright
laws faced reproduction and publication costs that were not significantly
lower than those of the original publisher. The nature of high-technology
products makes even their low-tech variations easier to copy than
ever before. For example, a cassette tape duplicator, made in the
U.S. and available in Brazil for US $4000, can make three bootleg
copies of a cassette tape simultaneously in ninety seconds.
U.S. firms find the strength of intellectual property protection
abroad to be a factor more important to the decision to invest in
a developing country than do firms from other countries in the industrialized
world. The U.S. is also the most aggressive country lobbying to
raise international standards of intellectual property protection:
67%. See Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development, Economic
Arguments for Protecting Intellectual Property Rights Effectively
171 (1988). Because U.S. exporters have more of a stake in protecting
intellectual property than do other industrialized countries, the
U.S.'s more pronounced assertiveness seems to be justified.
With so much at stake, it is no wonder that industrialized countries,
led by the U.S., have lobbied for protection of intellectual property
rights in the developing world to be on par with those in the industrialized
world. U.S. firms generating information-intensive technologies
for export have been demanding that the U.S. impose trade sanctions
or threaten to withdraw trade benefits as a way to punish developing
countries' unauthorized use of intellectual property.
Past experience has shown that the U.S. cannot protect the intellectual
property of its own nationals in the international arena through
domestic policy alone. On the other hand, international treaties
specifically devoted to intellectual property rights protection
have been largely ineffective in dealing with piracy in the developing
world. The most successful efforts, such as the Trade-Related Intellectual
Property Rights Agreement (TRIPS) of the Uruguay Round of the GATT,
have tied intellectual property protection to other issues such
as foreign trade.
Part II of this article will discuss the international agreements
that have been implemented to raise the standards of intellectual
property protection, and the policies used by the U.S. to create
incentives for foreign countries to respect U.S. intellectual property
rights. The article will also provide examples of the gains that
have been made and the problems that must still be addressed.
*Clarisa Long is the Abramson Fellow at the American Enterprise
Institute for Public Policy Research in Washington, D.C., where
she specializes in intellectual property law and the public policy
issues surrounding genetic research and the biotechnology industry.
She is also a Vice Chairman for Membership of the Intellectual Property
Practice Group.
|