Walter Olson*
The following remarks were delivered at the 1997 National Lawyers
Convention
In all the famous scenes in movies of recent years, there have
been few surer audience-pleasers than the one in Jurassic Park where
the dinosaur eats the lawyer. In my theater and Ill bet yours
too, the audience burst into laughter and cheers. So the question
we might start out with is: did audiences react the way they did
because Steven Spielberg had somehow been tainting their minds against
this great profession, slipping some subliminal message into his
movie saying it was okay to laugh at attorneys? Or did Spielberg
arrange the plot to get a lawyer munched like a cherry off the top
of a sundae because he knew perfectly well what would make audiences
laugh and cheer? In other words, do lawyers have an image problem
because Hollywood and the press have decided to pick on them, or
have Hollywood and the press decided to pick on lawyers because
they know the public already has a low opinion of them?
When I started out giving talks on whats wrong with the legal
system, I made a point of letting audiences know that I was not
(and am not) a lawyer. This started out as a simple disclaimer,
a warning that they should not expect certain types of professional
know-how from me. But though it may have begun as a warning, it
soon turned into an applause line. It gets me an enthusiastic response
from just about every audience thats not itself composed of
lawyers: from undergraduates and retirees, from doctors and homemakers,
from liberals and conservatives. Before long I refined the line
into "I'm not a lawyer, I just criticize them," which
often draws a one-word response, "Good!."
The current unpopularity of lawyers has been the subject of much
hand-wringing, and no little indignation, on the part of such groups
as the American Bar Association. To understand the ABAs official
wisdom on why lawyers are unpopular, you must first understand what
its wisdom does not hold. According to the ABA view, the prevailing
low regard for lawyers has nothing whatsoever to do with the publics
having noticed and reacted against any misconduct or hubris or overreaching
by the legal profession or the legal system itself. Certainly not.
Lawyers have plummeted in the occupational-esteem standings not
because lawyers do more destructive or useless things than they
used to, not because people think theyve nosed into too many
areas of American life, not because the system gives attorneys too
much power to inflict injury on their opponents, their clients and
third parties. No, its that the public has been terribly misled.
If it only knew more about how the American legal system worked,
it would not be so upset with lawyers. Its unfavorable view of lawyers
arises from misunderstanding, or, if you will, false consciousness.
If the problem is bad public relations, then the solution must
be better public relations. And so our bar establishment has labored
mightily to come up with talking points and slogans about the good
that lawyers do. One of my personal favorites is the official slogan
of the 1996 ABA national convention, "Freedom, Justice, Liberty
-- Without Lawyers Theyre Just Words." Or, to paraphrase
slightly: without lawyers, justice itself would be impossible. This
slogan delights me if only because it so irresistibly calls to mind
the slogan used by one of the big manufacturers of synthetic chemicals,
I believe, back in the 1970s, when terror about toxic substances
was everywhere: "Without chemicals, life itself would be impossible."
Of course in a sense this is a point very well taken: without oxygen
or water or salt wed all be in big trouble. Its just
that it may not seem very responsive to the grievance of someone
who lives downstream from a factory thats been dumping vinyl
chloride.
You see the same sorts of arguments in the campaigns done by other
interest groups that come under negative scrutiny from the press
and buy the lower righthand corner of the New York Times op-ed page
to talk back. "Without oil companies, driving itself would
be impossible" -- equally true, and equally far from satisfying
as an explanation for a big tanker spill. Or "without agribusiness,
eating itself would be impossible" -- this after some outbreak
of food poisoning. The public is smart enough to realize that whether
you accept that theres going to be an oil industry at all
is not the only question to be asked, and probably not the most
interesting question. It also wants to know, if you practice this
line of work: how careful are you to avoid spills, and how willing
are you to clean up when you do have one?
There are, of course, some more sophisticated theories as to why
lawyers' popularity stands so low. Let me call two of these the
dentist theory and the bartender theory.
The dentist theory, which Ive run across repeatedly, is that
people encounter lawyers at unhappy, downright painful times of
their lives. Theyve been indicted or are being audited or
are involved with a lawsuit. We all know that those are among the
most unpleasant things that happen to people, and so (according
to this theory) they transfer their pain into anger against those
who are physically present on the scene as they go through those
ordeals.
I disagree with the dentist theory, in part because, as Professor
Amy Black coincidentally documented in the research she described,
dentists themselves are not especially unpopular figures: most people
get along fine with dentists and arent especially critical
of that profession, even if they wince at the memory of what they
endured on their last visit. One reason, I think, is that the vast
majority of dentists try hard to minimize the pain they inflict.
People shop for dentistry services for themselves and their loved
ones, and so well does the market work that dentists compete with
each other not only as to quality of final work but also in promising
to reduce the pain to a bare minimum. They boast of being extra-considerate,
of practicing "gentle" dentistry, of "dentistry for
cowards." I have yet to see a billboard advertising "gentle
family lawyering", or painless lawyering, or "law for
cowards." Maybe those would be the ads for the mediation services.
But then when people buy "legal services" they are often
buying services to be inflicted on their current enemies, and services
that minimize unnecessary pain may not be what theyre looking
for.
Which brings us to the bartender theory, which is somewhat more
plausible and no doubt has at least a grain of truth in it. This
is the theory that clients, after all, actively seek out a lot of
the worst things that lawyers do. The vindictive spouse goes looking
for the carpet-bombing divorce lawyer; the business that wants to
stiff its creditors looks for the scorched-earth practitioner; the
person nursing a dubious personal injury claim looks for the lawyer
who is best at exaggerating. These clients may turn away the lawyer
who seems too gentle, too civilized, too considerate. When I got
to debate Alan Dershowitz on television, he was running into a lot
of flak from the audience at one stage because he had been discussing
his criminal defense practice, and some of the techniques that came
up, and of which he seemed to approve, struck the audience as taking
advantage of tricks or loopholes -- things like telling the client
on first meeting, don't tell me whether you're guilty or not, it
would tie my hands to know; leave me free to come up with the best
defense. The audience was not happy at all with that, but Dershowitz
came back with a line that did give them pause: he said go ahead
and boo, but if your child were arrested and charged with something,
you would want to go to a lawyer just like me.
As a predictive matter, surely he was right. Many or most of them
-- of us -- up against the wall, would call the lawyer whose ethical
code allowed him to, shall we say, retain a lot of options in vigorous
representation. I can't improve on Judge Laurence Silberman's great
line about this: just because we may play the horses doesn't mean
we have to respect bookies.
So, as I say, theres a grain of truth to the bartender analogy.
Many of us do head for the bartender who mixes the stiffest drinks,
rather than the drinks that may be best for our own health or societys.
(I trust you will henceforth have a new image in your mind when
you read about the leadership of "The Bar.") Nor are bartenders
or bookies the only occupations we might choose as analogous if
the function of lawyering is merely to cater to the frailties of
human nature. You might indeed raise the "tobacco company analogy";
those companies, too, respond to a genuinely preexisting consumer
demand, providing a product thats voluntarily bought even
if some of the customers may later regret buying it. To be sure
-- to revert to an earlier point -- no one is forced to drink beverages
or place bets or smoke cigarettes foisted on them by their adversaries.
Its worth keeping in mind, lest we be tempted to compare legal
practice to a market, that a majority of the consumers of the product
arent taking it voluntarily. No wonder we see so many Mickey
Finns and exploding cigars.
Any theory of the unpopularity of the legal profession must come
to grips with three observations:
One is that the unpopularity of the bar is not merely some lingering
prejudice hanging on in the least educated or worldly parts of society
among persons who may never have gotten to know lawyers or work
with them on a practical basis. Indeed, the evidence is abundant
and disturbing that the more continuing contact people have with
lawyers, the more vocal and fully formed a critique they tend to
give of them. Notoriously these days, doctors, accountants, and
practicing businesspeople are among the groups most upset with lawyers
and most convinced that self-regulation of the legal profession
has failed. This is not a matter of being unpopular because people
dont know you and only read about you in the papers.
Second -- and contra both the dentist theory and the bartender
theory -- lawyers have not always been unpopular as a profession.
If you trace this tension back through American history, in fact,
you find an interesting pattern: the abuses we see today are not
new, but they were formerly considered to be more on the fringe,
not typical of the profession. Nineteenth-Century America, especially
the turbulent big cities, did generate many celebrated criminal
cases in which, every so often, demagogic lawyers managed to spring
obviously guilty malefactors. And there were abuses in civil law,
including appeals to sympathetic local juries for unreasonably high
damage awards, that do seem to foreshadow elements of todays
runaway civil litigation. There was some solicitation and stirring
up of business by lawyers, and also hardball tactics of various
sorts. Yet there was a feeling that the legal profession as a whole
stood against such tactics, that the unscrupulous lawyer was an
exception looked down on by most in the profession and under pressure
from them. Now the public senses that the bad lawyer has much more
of an open field.
And third, the legal profession is vastly more respected in most
foreign countries, as it used to be here, though it goes without
saying that the operations of law are painful in other countries,
and though human nature, including the urge to sic a mean lawyer
on your opponent, is also nothing unique to America.
In short, the general norm throughout the world and even here until
recently has been for law to be a very highly respected profession,
one you would be pleased for your children to enter aside from the
likely financial rewards. It is recently, in the United States,
that the respect and prestige of the profession has fallen from
its historically high level.
So, what has happened in the last 20 or 30 years in the United
States? I try to give part of the answer, at least, in my 1991 book
The Litigation Explosion, endeavoring to detail some of the ways
weve drastically broken with many of the principles that had
long been thought suitable to govern a legal system and the legal
profession.
We have enacted countless new laws, we use them to try to control
more of life, and these laws are often vague, not clearly spelling
out what conduct is wrongful and what the legal consequences might
be of overstepping the line.
We have expanded damage theories to a point that we are willing
to countenance the mulcting of defendants of amounts that all previous
American generations and all foreign countries would consider sheerly
fantastic.
We have liberalized procedure. As long ago as the 1930s we began
to embrace the system of notice pleading, in which you can drag
someone to court without saying what he may have done wrong. In
the 1970s, we drastically liberalized discovery, making it far easier
to demand the filing cabinets of your opponent. Through the "long-arm"
jurisdiction revolution, we liberalized forum-shopping so that you
could shop around for whichever judge or jurisdiction is most hostile
to your opponent or most slanted in the direction of your own philosophy.
We liberalized the admission of expert testimony to allow lawyers
to keep a scientifically weak case alive by getting a partisan fringe
expert who does not represent the mainstream of whatever the discipline
is. And so on down the line.
At the same time, we were systematically revising the role we saw
the legal profession as playing in society, and not coincidentally
the rules of ethics that should govern it. There had always been
a balance between acting as an officer of the court, which might
call for refraining from many steps that advanced the interests
of ones client but not those of justice, and zealous representation,
red in tooth and claw. And now we have reached the point where many,
many authorities, not just practicing lawyers but also some professors
who specialize in legal ethics, are far more enthusiastic about
zealous representation and maintain that lawyers have no particular
duty of care to avoid misleading a factfinder or inflicting tactical
harm on an opponents or third partys pocketbook or reputation.
We have drastically liberalized lawyers' rights to take a share
in the claims they sue over, starting with the plaintiff's contingency
fee, but increasingly also through the development of contingency
fee arrangements on the defense and transactional side. Rather than
get along on boring old hourly fees, we now encourage them to get
rich if they obtain an unusually good result and go hungry if they
obtain an unusually bad one. By making the outcome one of feast
or famine rather than more versus some, we hyper-incentivize them
to do what it takes to win, even though many of those things are
far from attractive. And weve also drastically liberalized
the scope for class actions, citizen suits, and other actions which
encourage a lawyer to step forward with no real clients at all,
acting not as a friend to any particular client but only as a friend
to himself.
It's idle to say that the ethical dilapidation and the deprofessionalizing
trends are unrelated to the trends in procedure, evidence and damages,
because behind them all is a philosophy that lawsuits are basically
a good thing to be encouraged: the more litigation goes on, the
more justice we will see done.
The public disagrees with that, and it perceives that the result
of all these changes is not simply to encourage destructive wrangling
but also to give lawyers more power. Lawyers in America have more
power to ruin your life than they do in any other country. Nowhere
else can a lawyer show up, dump a pile of papers on your front lawn,
tie you up for years responding, do so much damage to your wealth
and reputation, and then walk away with as few consequences if he
is proven wrong. Lawyers, I submit, are so widely disliked in this
country because they are so very widely, and correctly, feared for
the power without responsibility they wield.
So the question I leave for the bar associations is: is your profession
disliked because its misunderstood? Or because its understood
too well?
*Walter Olson, senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute, is the
author of The Litigation Explosion (Plume) and The Excuse Factory
(Free Press). This is adapted from his speech at the National Convention
of the Federalist Society in October 1997.
|